Reduction of waste and electricity demand in the Netherlands
Reduction of waste and
electricity demand in the Netherlands: A hypothetical intervention
Slingerland, Stephan; Paulien De Jong. Journal of
Environmental Planning and Management 41.2 (Mar 1998): 195-208.
Slingerland, S., & Jong, P. D. (1998). Reduction of waste and electricity demand in the netherlands: A hypothetical intervention. Journal of Environmental Planning and Management, 41(2), 195-208. Retrieved from http://search.proquest.com/docview/
ABSTRACT A
n important question in the present reorganization and
liberalization of infrastructure networks in many countries is what kind of
regulatory regimes can provide incentives for demand management and reduction
in a future situation. In this paper, the present situation in the Dutch waste
and electricity sectors is analysed. It is concluded that a quantity-based
tariff system and the entwined interests of organizations are key impediments
to effective demand management in these two sectors. A hypothetical
intervention is proposed which aims to remove these two fundamental drawbacks.
Some likely consequences of the suggested intervention are discussed.
Introduction
In many countries, infrastructure networks have entered into
a process of rapid change. The aim of the current reorganization of sectors
such as electricity or water supply and waste disposal generally is to improve economic
efficiency by liberalizing these traditionally monopoly-based sectors (Wright,
1994). However, it is also increasingly realized by many national authorities
that a reduction of demand for the functions provided by infrastructure
networks would be desirable for environmental reasons. Hence, new regulatory
regimes have to be found which seek to combine the expected merits of
liberalization with incentives for demand management. Since the experiences
with these new organizational frameworks vary between countries and even
between sectors, cross-country and cross-sectoral comparisons can provide a
useful contribution to the international debate about what regulatory regimes
perform best.
In this paper, the demand management perspective is taken as
a starting point for analysing the Dutch waste and electricity sectors. After a
brief introduction to the method of analysis used, we describe the situation in
both sectors and analyse what fundamental constraints to reduction initiatives
can be found in both sectors. Finally we propose a hypothetical intervention
that aims at removing the fundamental constraints found and discuss some of its
likely consequences.
Method of Analysis
There are many ways to analyse the relationship between the
organization of infrastructure networks and demand reduction by organizations
within these networks. In particular the current restructuring of the
electricity sector has received much theoretical attention in this respect
(Hirst, 1994; Sioshansi, 1994; Intorcio, 1995). Also, many studies have been
published which focus on actual changes in regulatory regimes in one country
(Collier, 1995; Hvelplund, 1995; Surrey, 1996) or which compare regimes in two
or more countries (Bakken & Lucas, 1994; Walz, 1994).
However, the number of cross-sectoral studies in this debate
seems far less abundant (e.g. Guy & Marvin, 1996). As far as we know, no
generally applicable framework for such a cross-sectoral comparison has been
developed, so before analysing the Dutch waste and electricity sectors we will
give a brief outline of the methodology used in this paper.
Both waste and electricity sectors can be regarded as a
chain of 'functions'. We will distinguish four functions in the waste sector
and four in the electricity sector (Figure 1). In the waste sector, consumers
of goods produce discards. In this way, they are 'generators' of waste.
Discarded materials and products are collected and either processed or disposed
of directly. After processing, part of the former waste is reintroduced into
the product life-cycle as a useful product or material; the rest still has to
be disposed of. In the electricity sector, electricity is generated,
transmitted, distributed and finally consumed by end-users. An important
alternative is the direct generation of electricity by end-users. in particular
by so-called cogeneration (CHP) plants of industrial end-users.
Each of the functions distinguished can be carried out by an
organization whose only task is to perform this particular function. In this
case, the organizations are called unbundled. However, in practice it is quite
common for organizations to perform more than one function in the chain. This
is often referred to as vertical integration.
We will first analyse organizations performing a certain
function separately, as if they were unbundled. Our key question is: is it
economically attractive to organizations in the existing situation to stimulate
demand reduction initiatives? We will then turn to the consequences of the
existing, partly integrated situation.
The Dutch Waste and
Electricity Sectors
In this section, after a short historical outline, the
present situation in the Dutch waste and electricity sectors is described.
First, we look at the functions in the waste sector: disposal; processing;
collection; and consumption. Secondly, we turn to the electricity sector and
focus on generation, transmission, distribution and consumption. Finally, we
look at the vertical integration of these functions in both sectors.
The Waste Sector
The first attempts at a systematic collection of waste in
the Netherlands were private initiatives in the middle of the nineteenth
century. Municipalities granted concessions to these pioneering waste entrepreneurs
who started with household waste collection. This waste had an economic value:
it was almost purely organic and could in part be sold to farmers. At the
beginning of this century it was realized by authorities that waste collection
was of vital interest to citizens for hygienic reasons. Also, due to its
changed composition and the introduction of artificial fertilizers, waste
gradually lost its value. Hence, municipalities became more and more involved
in the organization of this infrastructural network (Tellegen et al., 1996).
Landfill became the most common way to dispose of waste, although due to the
shortage of suitable landfill locations, incineration of waste also began early
in the Netherlands.
In the 1970s, the increasing awareness of resource depletion
and environmental degradation gave rise to a policy which also included waste
reduction as a target. Over the last decades in particular an extensive network
for the separate collection and recycling of glass and paper has been set up.
In recent years, organic waste is also collected separately.
However, all recycling and waste reduction initiatives so
far have not resulted in a significant reduction of the quantity of household
waste sent for final disposal: in 1985 3 830 000 tonnes of waste had to be
disposed of, and in 1994 3 730 000 tonnes were sent for final disposal (RIVM,
1995).
Disposal. Most waste in the Netherlands is still landfilled.
However, incineration of waste now plays an important role in the final
disposal of household waste, in particular. In 1995, 35% of all household waste
was incinerated, almost as much as the percentage landfilled (41%). A quarter
(24%) of household waste was composted (RIVM et al., 1996). Tariffs for the
final disposal of waste are set by the number of units to be disposed of (Epema
Committee, 1996). As a result of this financial mechanism, none of the
organizations involved in final disposal of waste gets an incentive to reduce
waste production from an economic point of view. This holds in particular for
waste incinerators which do have very high investment costs and correspondingly
long write-off periods.
In fact, rather than stimulate demand reduction,
incinerators have a financial interest in attracting waste. In particular,
competition for waste from industry and commerce between incinerators in the
Netherlands presently occurs which results in shipments of waste from one
province to another. A newly built incinerator in the province of Gelderland,
for instance, with a capacity of 240 000 tonnes was expecting to incinerate
only 70-80 000 tonnes in 1996 and tried to get waste from the Northern
provinces. It even tried to get contracts for waste from Germany (Wester,
1996). Only an intervention of the Ministry of the Environment finally
prevented the import of German waste (Huisman, 1996).
Processing. After the collection of waste, part of the waste
stream is processed and recycled. For instance, in 1993 76% of all glass and
66% of all paper collected from households was recycled (CBS, 1994). Profits of
the generally privately operated processors depend on the number of units of
waste processed. This could be an economic incentive for them to stimulate
consumers to separate certain categories of waste for processing. It is not,
however, financially attractive to them to promote waste reduction by
end-users. This would, if successful, reduce the total amount of waste
produced, which would generally also affect the amount of waste to be processed
(de Jong & Wolsink, 1997). Collection. Waste collection from captive
customers, generally households and small-scale enterprises, is the
responsibility of municipalities. Tariffs for waste collection from captive
customers are flat, i.e. not dependent on the quantity of waste produced. They
are also cost-plus based, which means that collectors can reimburse their costs
and make a certain, regulatory approved, profit per unit of waste. Since, in
this case, there is no direct link between the total quantity of waste
collected and profitability, economic efficiency considerations do not
necessarily provide incentives to the operators of captive waste collection to
increase the amount of waste collected. It could be argued that, for economic
reasons, they have a stimulus to actually reduce the quantity of waste
collected, since their profits are not dependent on this quantity whereas their
costs are. However, this is only partly true since, as a result of the existing
monopoly, they can reimburse their costs by charging higher tariffs to their
captive customers.
The collection of waste from non-captive customers, on the
other hand, is mostly privately operated and profits of private investors
depend on the volume of waste collected. In order to increase profits, these
collectors would be stimulated by a financial mechanism to collect more waste.
Consumption. Tariffs for captive waste collection are
non-quantity based. Hence, in theory these consumers do not have an economic
incentive to reduce their waste production. Despite the fact that recycling
rates in the Netherlandsin particular of glass and paper-are already high,
experiments with quantitybased tariffs for households show that the quantity of
waste sent for final disposal can still be reduced significantly. In 1994, it
was estimated on the basis of the preliminary data of several pilot projects
that a reduction of 50-70% of household waste sent for final disposal could be
obtained as a result of providing new possibilities for separate collection, in
particular of organic waste, in combination with quantity-based tariffs (IPH,
1994). More recent figures are less optimistic, but nevertheless show a range
of 15-60% waste reduction (IPH, 1995). Non-captive consumers, generally larger
enterprises and industry, already pay per unit.
The Electricity
Sector
In the nineteenth century, some private companies in the
Netherlands started with electricity supply on a very limited scale. Similarly
to the waste sector, municipalities took over the initiative as soon as the
importance of this infrastructural network for the public was realized. Many
local and regional networks developed, which in the 1950s were connected to
form one national grid (Tellegen et al., 1996). Over the last decades a
continuous process of reorganization took place in Dutch electricity supply, of
which the most important features were the ever increasing scales of
organizations as a result of mergers, the formal unbundling of generation and
distribution in 1989, and the present gradual liberalization of the market.
Demand management became a policy item in 1973, when the
first comprehensive energy policy plan was published. In recent years,
distribution companies became the main actors responsible for these demand
reduction activities. Despite some undoubted successes, electricity demand in
the Netherlands continues to rise. Over the last 10 years, electricity demand
via the national grid has risen from under 60 TWh/annum in 1986 to almost 80
TWh in 1996 (Sep, 1997). Generation. Like incinerators in the waste sector, electricity
generators do have high investment costs which require full operation of built
generation capacity. For instance, UNA, one of the four Dutch generation
companies, invested 356 million Dutch guilders in 1995 to build just three new
plants (UNA, 1996).
In recent years, the four electricity generating companies
in the Netherlands have made large efforts to reduce emissions. An improvement
of conversion efficiency, which is also in their own economic interest, has
contributed to emission reduction as well. Nevertheless generators still have
an interest in selling more electricity, since their receipts are based on the
number of kWh actually supplied to distribution utilities. In the past, this
was of less importance since, due to the monopoly situation (from which only
very large consumers were excluded), all costs could easily be passed on to the
distributors who, in turn, charged the captive consumers. However, since the
1980s, the pressure on the net profit of the generation companies is growing, in
particular due to the boom of combined heat and power installations owned by
industrial endusers-even more so, since the coming liberalization of the
European electricity market requires a higher solvency of generators than so
far. A reduction of this pressure can be obtained on the one hand by reducing
costs, on the other hand by trying to increase sales. Of the four central power
producers in the Netherlands, UNA was the only company that managed to increase
electricity sales in 1995. It was also this company that saw net profit
increase by the highest percentage: 22% (UNA/EPON/EPZ/EZH, 1996).
Transmission. The organization responsible for operating the
transmission network acts as an intermediary between power production and the
supply of electricity to end-users. The tariff system for transmission is
complicated, but in essence the operator buys electricity from the four
generation companies and sells it to distributors, adding its own operational
and transmission costs. In this way, the profits of transmission are directly
linked to the number of units transmitted. This relationship is even more
evident as the transmission organization in the Netherlands is also responsible
for power production planning.
In fact, the Dutch transmission organization is involved in
stimulating electricity demand, although this is motivated for environmental
reasons. In the Electricity Plan 1997-2006 it is noted that: "Energy
conservation policy is directed at efficient application of electric energy,
which comprises both electricity conservation and energy conservation directed
application of electricity" (Sep, 1996, p. 15: italics added). The
introduction of electric cars, for instance, which is promoted by this
organization, would lead to reduced COz emissions but increased electricity
demand, according to a study initiated by this organization (Sep, 1994).
Distribution. Distribution tariffs for both captive and
non-captive consumers are unit-based. Hence, distributors would not find it
economically attractive to stimulate electricity demand reduction. The fact
that they are nevertheless presently involved in demand reduction activities
seems to contradict this thesis. It has to be noted, however, that these
activities are financed externally, predominantly by a levy charged to captive
consumers on top of the ordinary electricity tariffs. Also, these activities up
to now have resulted at best in a reduced growth of electricity demand, rather
than in a reduction of demand. They thus hardly interfere with the economic activities
of distribution utilities.
The duality in the tasks of distribution companies
stimulating, on the one hand, electricity conservation and, on the other hand,
gaining profits from selling exactly this commodity is, for instance,
illustrated in the documents of the distribution company EDON. The
Environmental Action Plan of this company states that: "Environmental
policy has been for some years a priority of EDON. The company acknowledges its
responsibility for the environment and stimulates energy conservation and a
'cleaner' energy-use since three years with selected measures" (EDON,
1994, p. 3). On the other hand, the Economic Account over the same year says:
"Compared to 1993, an improved result of 11.9 million Dutch guilders has
been obtained. The higher gross margin on electricity due to increasing sales
as well as lower cost prices, and stabilised personnel and amortization costs,
contributed in particular to this positive development" (EDON, 1995, p.
15: italics added). Consumption. Captive as well as non-captive consumers are
charged per unit. Hence, it would be financially attractive to them to try to
limit their demand for electricity. In recognition of the price responsitivity
of consumers, since 1996 a unit-based tax has been charged on top of the normal
tariffs with the explicit aim of reducing demand. Nevertheless, short term
price-elasticity of electricity demand appears low. In a study carried out some
years ago it was estimated that household electricity demand would decrease by
only 12% if electricity tariffs were doubled (SEO, 1992).
Vertical Integration
in the Waste and Electricity Sector
Due to high investment costs, in particular for incinerators
and generators, a guaranteed income is important for the waste and electricity
sectors. As a result, they have an interest in a constant, or preferably
increasing, waste stream and electricity demand. If they are organizationally
linked to, or integrated with, organizations performing other functions in the
chain, it can be anticipated that they will use their influence to guard this
interest.
In both sectors, such an integrated situation presently
exists. In the waste sector, incinerators are operated by municipalities, who
are also responsible for waste collection. Funds for new incineration capacity
are raised by municipalities together with private bodies. In the long run,
therefore, municipalities are substantially involved in carrying the financial
risk of operating incinerators.
On the other hand, municipalities are involved in regulation,
notably in setting tariffs for the collection of captive waste. As a result of
this position, municipalities can pass on costs associated with the
incineration and collection of captive waste to households. Or, as one employee
of the municipality of Amsterdam noted when interviewed about waste reduction:
"The principal result of a reduced waste production in one year would be a
rise in incineration tariffs in the following year" (de Jong &
Wolsink, 1993, p. 29). Since waste reduction initiatives, which could be
financially attractive to municipalities as collectors, are not attractive to
those same municipalities as the organizations carrying the financial risk of
incineration plant, any waste reduction initiatives on financial grounds are
therefore likely to be nipped in the bud. In the electricity sector,
distribution and generation of electricity were legally unbundled in 1989.
Nevertheless close links via ownership still exist; municipalities and
provinces own distributors, distributors own generators, and the generators
jointly own the transmission organization. These links will even be tightened
in future, as the most recent plans suggest. The four generators will merge to
one generation company, with shares completely in the hands of distributors (EZ,
1996).
The recent developments concerning the growth of highly
efficient, `environmentally friendly' CHP capacity illustrate the pressure
generators can exert on the system due to their links with other functions in
the electricity chain. After the unbundling of distribution and generation, a
competition between these two functions arose in which the distribution
companies stimulated industrial endusers to install CHP plants. These were
interesting to distributors for environmental as well as economic reasons. On
one hand, these plants contributed substantially to the COz emission reduction
goals distributors had set in their environmental action plans. On the other
hand, electricity from cogeneration plants proved to be, in many cases, cheaper
than electricity from central generation companies.
However, in 1994 due to the unexpected overwhelming success
of CHP, an overcapacity of generation capacity was anticipated by the planning
organization. Although alternative solutions would have been possible, for
instance a quicker phasing out of central capacity, it was decided, in an
agreement between the planning organization, central power producers and
distributors, to cut back the growth in CHP capacity, mainly leaving central
power production largely untouched. Apparently, the four large-scale power
producers managed to bring about this agreement in their favour, despite the
remaining interests of distributors as well as industrial end-users in CHP. It
is doubtful whether this agreement would have been brought about without the
links of central generators to the planning organization (Slingerland, 1996).
A Hypothetical Intervention Although the waste and
electricity sector certainly differ in many respects, in the previous sections
we have argued that they are equal in at least two ways which, in our view,
represent fundamental drawbacks to demand-reduction initiatives.
Firstly, for almost all actors, costs and income are related
to the quantity of waste and electricity that is handled by them. In Table 1
this is worked out in some detail. We have also noticed that, as a result, they
do not receive financial incentives for demand reduction initiatives. One
notable exception is the tariffs charged by waste collectors to captive
consumers. Secondly, we have noted that the importance of constant waste flow
and electricity demand is particularly relevant to incinerators and generators
as a result of their high investment costs. In both sectors, the interests of
these actors are also represented in other functions of the waste and
electricity chain due to the entwined ownership and operational relations.
Many regulatory interventions are possible to counteract
these two, in our opinion, fundamental drawbacks to reduction initiatives.
Also, many regulatory measures aimed at stimulating reduction initiatives in
the infrastructure networks we examined have already been taken. However, given
the fact that the quantity of waste offered for final disposal has not
decreased, and electricity demand continues to increase, one can question
whether the measures that have been taken in the two sectors we examined are
really effective.
In line with other authors, who suggest that more
fundamental changes in regulatory regimes of infrastructure networks are needed
to provide incentives for demand reduction (e.g. Verbruggen, 1994), we want to
propose such an intervention. It is derived from and applied to the two
infrastructure networks we examined. However, as we limit ourselves to some key
general features, we believe it is worthwhile considering whether it might be
applicable to other infrastructure networks as well.
Our analysis suggests that an unbundling of organizations
which perform more than one function, and a decoupling of profits of
organizations from the quantity of waste or electricity handled, would provide
a remedy against the problems found. On the one hand, the second part of the
suggested intervention seems to contradict economic principles. It is, however,
already applied in practice in one part of the waste sector we examined:
tariffs for captive-waste collection are non-quantity based, as we have noted.
Since the income of waste collectors is not related to the quantity of waste
collected, whereas their costs are, in theory they would have a financial
incentive to stimulate consumers to reduce the quantity of waste offered for
collection and final disposal. However, a condition for this incentive to hold
is a competitive situation. In the present monopoly situation any collectors'
costs can be simply reimbursed by a higher tariff charged to captive consumers.
Therefore a third element to an intervention would be needed: the introduction
of competition. This would also be in line with trends in both sectors that are
currently emerging. If collectors, and correspondingly distributors, received a
fixed allowance per customer, competition would have to concentrate on reducing
costs and increasing service. Collectors/distributors could reduce their costs
by stimulating consumers to reduce waste production and electricity demand.
On the other hand, flat tariffs, which would normally result
from the fixed allowance to collectors/distributors, would not give an
incentive to consumers to reduce waste production and electricity demand. To
combine a quantitybased charge to consumers with a fixed allowance to
collectors/distributors, establishment of an intermediate financial facility
would be needed to which consumers pay their bills and from which
collectors/distributors receive their allowances. A municipally-administered
demand management fund could provide such a facility. A condition would be a
strict curtailment of municipalities to this task, leaving the remaining
functions in the waste and electricity sectors to other organizations in order
to prevent a complexity of interests. Hence, the proposed intervention consists
of five elements: (1) unbundling of functions;
(2) introduction of competition on the collector/distributor
level; (3) fixed allowance, non-quantity based, to collectors/distributors; (4)
quantity-based bill to consumers;
(5) establishment of a municipally-administered demand
management fund. In Table 2 the tariff system we propose is worked out. In
addition, an example for calculation of tariffs in the new system is given in
Table 3. We want to show, by a simplified example, that waste reduction, after
the suggested intervention, is financially attractive to collectors and
households, though not to incinerators. Profits after intervention, as compared
to the existing situation, are shown. After the proposed regulatory
intervention, collectors/distributors would act as an independent buffer
between the interests of incinerators/generators and the consumers. As a result
of the fixed allowance, it would be in their interest to stimulate consumers to
reduce waste production and electricity demandcontrary to the interests of
incinerators and generators. The allowance, in our view, would have to be based
on the average waste production and electricity demand per consumer. Obviously,
this can only work if the differences between consumers are not too large.
Hence, customers would have to be divided into categories. Judged from the
present situation for captive consumers in the waste sector, households could
represent one category. Other categories could be small-scale businesses and
various categories of industry for instance.
Municipalities could be the actors administering the funds
to which consumers pay their bills. They would have to sign contracts for their
area for which the collectors/distributors would have to compete. By estimating
in advance what the average demand in a municipality for the various categories
of consumers in the contract period would be, collectors/distributors could
determine against what allowance they would be willing to collect waste or
supply electricity. The lower the average estimated, the cheaper the contract
they could offer.
After a contract had been signed, the municipality could
determine the tariff charged to customers that was needed in order to maintain
the fund from which the allowance to collectors/distributors would be paid. Any
surpluses from the fund could be used for additional financing of
demand-reduction initiatives.
Although this proposal might seem far-fetched, it should be
mentioned that, on a small scale, pilot projects with such demand reduction
funds are already being undertaken in the Netherlands. In one southern province,
quick scans for waste reduction possibilities at commercial enterprises are
paid from a fund which is financed by the province and other organizations. If
the quick scan reveals economic waste reduction options, its costs (plus a
certain amount that is used to refill the fund) have to be paid by the
enterprise; otherwise the quick scan is free of charge (Verspeek et al., 1996).
Discussion and Conclusions Having introduced and described the suggested
intervention, we want now to discuss some of its consequences. These are
obviously hard to predict for such a drastic change, but we will try to address
three key questions: (1) does the proposed intervention result in an incentive
for demand reduction, i.e. is it effective?; (2) is it economically efficient?;
and (3) does it interfere with the reliability of service provided?
Effectiveness. Looking at the actors that have been
highlighted, the intervention is meant to give incentives for demand reduction
to collectors/distributors and to consumers as a result of the proposed changes
in the tariff system. The intervention does not give incentives to
incinerators/generators nor to processing/transmission organizations to
stimulate demand reduction.
A possible drawback on the consumer level could lie in the
price-elasticity of demand. The intervention is based on the supposition that
consumers will indeed reduce their waste production if charged by quantity. The
experience in this respect in the waste sector is limited to a few pilot
projects. In the electricity sector, where tariffs are already based on
quantity, short term price-elasticity of demand appears low. On the other hand,
consumers do not so much ask for electricity itself as for the tasks that can
be performed with it, such as lighting, using audio-visual equipment, etc. That
there are substantial possibilities for efficiency improvement which would
reduce electricity demand is suggested by various research projects (e.g. WNF,
1994) and also acknowledged by policy makers (EZ, 1995).
A strong emphasis is put on the activities of
collectors/distributors who have to initiate reduction initiatives out of
financial self-interest. If the intervention is to be effective, it is crucial
in this respect that their position is strong enough to counteract tendencies
against reduction which are likely to come from the incineration/generation
level. A strict unbundling, including unbundling of ownership relations, is
needed to prevent mixed interests here. Economic efficiency. The intention of
the intervention is to create incentives for economic efficiency through the
introduction of competition at the collector/ distributor level. These actors
have to compete for contracts to be signed with municipalities who administer
the funds. On the other hand, the introduction of an additional financial level
between consumers and collectors/distributors could result in increased
bureaucracy which would interfere with economic efficiency.
Paradoxically, economic efficiency is also possibly
endangered by the effectiveness of the intervention. If the intervention is
effective, and a substantial demand reduction occurs, the income of the fund
that is meant to cover the allowances to collectors/distributors might not be
sufficient to cover the expenses. In addition, through the introduction of
quantity-based tariffs, the anti-social behaviour of consumers-such as
littering in the waste sector-is stimulated. The control that would be needed
to prevent this kind of behaviour also interferes with economic efficiency.
Reliability. The essential point concerning reliability of service in both
sectors is whether collectors/distributors would be willing to sign contracts
with municipalities that for some reason (e.g. high average consumption, low
allowance offered) appear less attractive to them. This problem is shared with
all competitive systems where an equilibrium between supply and demand has to
be found in the market. An obligation for municipalities to assure a reliable
waste collection and electricity supply would help to increase reliability,
although it cannot be ruled out that, in some cases, reliability would be
endangered. On the other hand, the extent to which a service is reliable will
also be an aspect of competition-selecting those collectors/distributors that
offer the right balance between price and reliability.
Summarizing, the main advantages of the proposed
intervention, in our view, are the financial incentives to
collectors/distributors and to consumers for demand reduction, as well as the
incentives for economic efficiency by the introduction of competition at the
collector/distributor level. Major disadvantages are the likely increased
bureaucracy and the possible anti-social behaviour of consumers. Another
disadvantage could be the reduced reliability of the system which would result
from the introduction of competition. Obviously, further research is necessary
to work out in detail the consequences of the hypothetical intervention
proposed here. Nevertheless, given the limited effects of regulatory regimes aiming
to stimulate reduction initiatives so far, we think it is useful to carry the
debate about the role of demand reduction in infrastructure networks along less
conventional lines.
Acknowledgements
The authors wish to thank Jan Eberg, Wim Gilijamse, Brigitte
Hertz, Annelies Huijgen, Herman Huisman, Lucas Reijnders, Peter Renaud, Egbert
Tellegen and Maarten Wolsink for their useful comments and recommendations.
Also we very much appreciated the discussion with the participants of the
Energy Workshop of the 1996 Greening of Industry Conference in Heidelberg,
Germany, where we presented a paper containing the initial ideas that led to
this paper.
Komentar
Posting Komentar